Food Intake: Impacts on Nutrition and Health in Mali

agec 640 agricultural policy september 13 2018 n.w
1 / 20
Embed
Share

Explore the complexities of food demand and nutrition in Mali, uncovering how imperfect information, market failures, and societal factors influence food intake and child health outcomes. Discover the critical link between child mortality and nutritional deficits, shedding light on the challenges faced by infants in accessing high-nutrient density foods for optimal growth and development.

  • Food intake
  • Nutrition
  • Child health
  • Market failures
  • Mali

Uploaded on | 0 Views


Download Presentation

Please find below an Image/Link to download the presentation.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author. If you encounter any issues during the download, it is possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

You are allowed to download the files provided on this website for personal or commercial use, subject to the condition that they are used lawfully. All files are the property of their respective owners.

The content on the website is provided AS IS for your information and personal use only. It may not be sold, licensed, or shared on other websites without obtaining consent from the author.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. AGEC 640 Agricultural Policy September 13, 2018 Nutrition and Food Markets Extra slides on imperfect information & food demand not delivered in class Reading: Masters and Sanogo, 2002 in AJAE

  2. Now what else might be useful to understand food intake? Food is a public concern, but it is not a public good Food demand generate subtle kinds of market failures One reason is that its benefits are important but often delayed and often not observable, so we have: credit and insurance constraints (the poor can t borrow) behavioral effects (people are predictably irrational) weak self-discipline (addiction, obesity, etc.) distorted perceptions (anxiety, obsession, etc.) asymmetric information (need quality assurance) example of Masters and Sanogo (2002) study of infant foods in Bamako, Mali

  3. Weight-for-height (WHZ) and height-for-age (HAZ) of children in Mali, relative to international norms 1.0 Std. Dev. of Reference Population .5 The most severe nutritional deficits occur in a relatively brief period 0.0 -.5 -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 Mean WHZ -2.5 -3.0 Mean HAZ 0 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24 27 30 33 Age in Months Source: Demographic and Health Survey, 1995/96

  4. Child mortality is closely linked to their weight-for-height Source: Reprinted from Fawzi, W.W., M.G. Herrera, D.L. Spiegelman, A.E. Amin, P. Nestel, and K.A. Mohamed. 1997. A Prospective Study of Malnutrition in Relation to Child Mortality in the Sudan. The American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 65(4): 1062-9.

  5. Why are nutritional deficits so severe between 4 and 24 months of age? exposure to disease due to initial introduction of water and solids, or perhaps also more mobility and contact with others; deficits in nutrient intake due to differences between infant and family foods, and failure to provide enough infant-quality foods.

  6. Characteristics of infant foods Infants need foods of higher nutrient density than the family diet, from when they outgrow the nutrients in breastmilk to when they can digest enough of the family diet. High density is obtained from high-cost ingredients (oilseeds or animal products), mixed with low-cost staples (cereal grains, etc.) but parents cannot observe an infant food s ingredient ratios and density, even after consumption, because other factors affect growth

  7. Economics of credence goods Akerlof (1970) and others: If quality is unobservable, quantity will be zero! optimizing people will not respond to price except as remedied by trust in a brand. ==> sellers use advertising and high prices as visible commitments to quality, so buyers must pay a premium over known costs, to buy guaranteed quality, e.g. premiums paid for brand-name lawyers, pharmacists, auto mechanics, etc.

  8. Table 1. Infant foods for sale in Bamako, Mali (1999) Brand name Packaging C r lac (wheat) 400 g. can C r lac (wheat) 200 g. box C r lac (rice) 400 g. can C r lac (wheat/Banana) 400 g. can C r lac (wheat +3 fruits) 400 g. can Bl dilac** (wheat) 250 g. can Bl dina** lact e fruits 250 g. box Farinor** (maize/soy) 400 g. box MISOLA 500 g. bag UCODAL (e.g. Sinba) 200 g. bag Retail Prices (FCFA/unit)* Mkt. Stores Pharmacy 1400 1500 1615 600 1600 1750 850 2240 1270 1830 1690 1750 300 200 Source: Masters and Sanogo, 2002.

  9. Economics of credence goods (continued) Akerlof (1970) saw an alternative remedy to lower the cost of credence goods: third-party certification mandatory testing => complete coverage examples: FDA, USDA limitations: tax-funded, incentive for fraud fee-for-service => self-sustaining, self-policing examples: ISO, UL limitations: scale economies, may not emerge spontaneously

  10. Benefits and Costs of Certification in Mali 1. benefits of certification what is food-quality information really worth? do some mothers value information more than others? 2. costs of certification what are set-up and marginal costs? what volume would be certified? 3. net gains from certification do they justify the investment risks? would the program be sustainable?

  11. To detect what certification is worth, we need a experimental economics.. Vickrey (1961) and others: Preference-revealing auctions mimic real markets: price is fixed by others; choice is to accept or decline M&S experiment is aimed at very, very low-income people -- avoids using money, so choice is among infant foods only; avoids calculations, so choice is easy and natural: give mothers a can of Cerelac offer to swap for increasing quantities of substitute products record whether they accept or decline each choice give them one of their choices, selected at random The design is not quite strategy-proof; respondents may hold out for slightly more of each substitute than in ideal auction

  12. Summary statistics for willingness-to-pay results WTP (FCFA per 400 g.) ave. 1500.00 (market price) 1159.83 357.77 667 704.59 210.36 462 119.14 35.07 75 251.22 0 585.45 213.97 312 s.d. min. max. WTP by product 1. Cerelac 2. Certilac 3. Anonymous product 4. Raw ingredients WTP for premium for 2 over 3: Certification 455.24 for 3 over 4: Processing 1500 1500 150 1038 1425

  13. So certification has large benefits but what would be its cost? 10 million FCFA/month for advertising 1 m. FCFA/mo. per 50 tests/mo. for staffing 0.6 m FCFA/mo. per 20 tests/mo. for transport 3,520 FCFA/mo. per test for consumables 1,000 x 400g. sold per test done => cost falls below ave. WTP at 30,000 bags/mo. => cost falls below 100 FCFA at 215,000 /mo.

  14. How much food would be certified? 50,000 children aged 6-24 months in Bamako 100 g./day average consumption per child => 8 bags of 400 g. per month low scenario: 39% use (now using Cerelac) high scenario: 89% use (now using any food) => total potential is 155,000 350,000 bags/mo.

  15. Would certifications benefits exceed its costs? Two ways to estimate: (1) Each respondent has a different WTP Some respondents WTP below cost Construct demand curves & optimal quantity Find economic surplus (2s) All respondents have identical WTP Average WTP is way above cost Full market size is certified Find total benefits - costs

  16. Estimated certification demand and average-cost curves 1200 Certification Cost (FCFA/400 g. bag) 1000 800 c d g 600 400 200 b a e f 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 Thousands 400 Quantity Sold (400 g. bags/month) Demand-Case 1 Demand-Case 2 Cost of Cert.

  17. Table 3. Consumer surplus and net benefit from certification Case 1 Case 2 Consumer surplus approach Equilibrium qty. certified Net economic surplus gain (FCFA/month) Net economic surplus gain (US$/year) Cost-benefit analysis approach Total estimated market size (400 g. bags/mo.) 154,746 Net economic benefit/month (FCFA/month) Net economic surplus gain (US$/year) (400 g. bags/mo.) 150,000 345,000 51,543,984 134,029,438 951,581 2,474,390 353,138 51,713,454 132,138,264 954,710 2,439,476

  18. OK, so quality information is needed should testing be voluntary or mandatory? Private solutions work if a certifier can force users to pay (that is, exclude free-riders), e.g.: Underwriters Laboratories (sellers pay for label) Consumer Reports, CarFax (buyers pay each time) and thereby capture enough revenue to pay the cost of obtaining the information; while maintaining a credible quality signal of their own! Often it s cheaper to use the government: value capture from consumers can occur through taxation (e.g. USDA grades) or user fees (e.g. air traffic) quality-destroying competition can be barred by mandatory standards and licensing but the quality being upheld may not be valued by consumers; standards may be just an entry barrier to protect insiders

  19. Some conclusions Food intake decisions involve not only observable attributes (taste, texture, color), but also unobservable qualities and delayed effects. Food choices can be hard to understand using economics on observable prices and quantities only so sometimes we need inferences and experiments but much of the irrationality in food consumption can be understood as constrained optimization this allows us to plan public interventions that raise welfare, even though food is not a public good.

Related


More Related Content